A comparison of Inter-Organizational Business Models of Mobile App Stores: There is more than Open vs Closed

Référence :  Müller R.L., Kijl B., Martens J.K.J. (2011) « A comparison of Inter-Organizational Business Models of Mobile App Stores: There is more than Open vs Closed » in Journal of Theoretical and Applied Electronic Commerce Research, Vol. 6, n°2, pp. 63-76.

Idée dominante : La concurrence entre les app stores pour smartphone permet de distinguer plusieurs types de stratégies plus complexe que la différentiation binaire de technologie ouverts/fermés.

Résumé :

La différentiation stratégique des plateformes mobile se limitait jusqu’à présent à l’opposition entre technologie ouverte et fermée. D’autres typologies prennent en compte d’autres dimensions pour différencier les plateformes : contrôle/accès à une ressource ; contrôle des actifs/contrôle des clients ; Verticale (prix, qualité)/Horizontale (type d’utilisateurs).

Plusieurs modèles théoriques sont également à prendre en compte car ils ont un impact sur la structure d’un app store (Effets de réseaux, économies d’échelles, coûts de transaction). De même, des mécanismes assurant de la qualité sont mis en œuvre pour réduire les risques liés aux transactions entre développeurs et consommateurs (construction de réputation, systèmes de réputation, garanties, prévisualisation, comptes rendus). De nouveaux business models sont aussi expérimentés par les développeurs (achats in-app).

Les auteurs mettent en place une modélisation (E3 Value Model) pour mettre en avant les interdépendances entre les activités et acteurs de l’écosystème des app stores. Sur cette modélisation générale, la source principale de rentrée d’argent provient des consommateurs et des fournisseurs de publicité alors que les sorties d’argents sont principalement destinées aux développeurs et distributeurs de logiciels. Le propriétaire de l’app store peut influencer ce réseau de valeur en le structurant et en décidant des rôles qu’il va contrôler ou non et de leur exclusivité. L’analyse des différents app store selon ce modèle et le concept d’innovation ouverte et d’ « innovation economies of scope » a permis de déterminer qu’une plateforme n’est ni totalement fermée et ni totalement ouverte car certains services sont ouverts ou fermés selon le business model sous-jacent de la plateforme.

Notes d’intérêt : Texte fondamental car contenant beaucoup de concepts théoriques appliqués spécifiquement au marché des app stores (avec notamment modélisation e3 du réseau de valeur de ce marché). Il donne également des éléments de comparaison entre les différents app stores avec un focus sur Apple et Google.

Références bibliographiques :

[1] H. Achterhuis, De utopie van de vrije markt (Dutch). Rotterdam: Uitgeverij Lemniscaat, 2010.

[2] G. A. Akerlof, The market for “lemons”: Quality uncertainty and the market mechanism, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 84, no. 3, pp. 488-500, 1970.

[3] M. M. Al-Debei and D. Avison, Developing a unified framework of the business model concept, European Journal of Information Systems, vol. 19, no. 3, pp. 359-376, 2010.

[4] K. Andrew. (2011, March) BlackBerry App World doing 3 million downloads a day, Pocket Gamer.Biz [Online]. Available: http://www.pocketgamer.biz/r/PG.Biz/BlackBerry+App+World/news.asp?c=28631.

[5] K. Boudreau, Open platform strategies and innovation: Granting access vs. devolving control, Management Science, vol. 56, no. 10, pp. 1849-1872, 2010.

[6] H. Bouwman, E. Faber, T. Haaker, B. Kijl, and M. De Reuver, Conceptualizing the STOF Model, in Mobile Service Innovation and Business Models, H. Bouwman, T. Haaker, and H. De Vos, Eds. Berlin: Springer Verlag, 2008, pp. 31-70.

[7] H. Chesbrough, Open business models: How to thrive in the new innovation landscape, MA: Harvard Business
School Press, 2006.

[8] H. Chesbrough and R. S. Rosenbloom, The role of the business model in capturing value from innovation: evidence from Xerox Corporation’s technology spin-off companies, Industrial and Corporate Change, vol. 11, no. 3, pp. 529-555, 2002.

[9] H. W. Chesbrough, Open innovation: The new imperative for creating and profiting from technology, MA: Harvard Business Press, 2003.

[10] M. De Reuver, Governing mobile service innovation in co-evolving value networks, Delft: Delft University of Technology, 2009.

[11] C. Dellarocas, Immunizing online reputation reporting systems against unfair ratings and discriminatory behavior, in Proceedings of the 2nd ACM conference on Electronic commerce, Minneapolis, 2000, pp. 150-157.

[12] D. S. Evans and R. Schmalensee, The industrial organization of markets with two-sided platforms, Competition Policy International, vol. 3, no. 1, pp. 151-179, 2007.

[13] E. J. Friedman and P. Resnick, The social cost of cheap pseudonyms, Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, vol. 10, no. 2, pp. 173-199, 2001.

[14] Gartner. (2010, August) Gartner says worldwide mobile device sales grew 13.8 percent in second quarter of 2010, but competition drove prices down. [Online]. Available: http://www.gartner.com/it/page.jspid=1421013.

[15] Gartner. (2011, April) Press Release: Gartner Says Android to Command Nearly Half of Worldwide Smartphone Operating System Market by Year-End 2012. [Online]. Available: http://www.gartner.com/it/page.jsp?id=1622614.

[16] V. Gonçalves, N. Walravens, and P. Ballon, “How about an App Store?” Enablers and constraints in platform strategies for mobile network operators, in Proceedings of International Conference on Mobile Business (ICMB) and Global Mobility Roundtable (GMR), Athens, Greece, 2010, pp. 66-73.

[17] J. Gordijn and H. Akkermans, Designing and evaluating e-business models, Intelligent Systems, IEEE, vol. 16, no. 1, pp. 11-17, 2001.

[18] J. Hedman and T. Kalling, The business model concept: theoretical underpinnings and empirical illustrations, European Journal of Information Systems, vol. 12, no. 1, pp. 49-59, Mar 2003.

[19] A. Jusang, R. Ismail, and C. Boyd, A survey of trust and reputation systems for online service provision, Decision Support Systems, vol. 43, no. 2, pp. 618-644, 2007.

[20] M. L. Katz and C. Shapiro, Systems competition and network effects, The Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol. 8, no. 2, pp. 93-115, 1994.

[21] J. Kincaid. (2011, January) Amazon’s disruptive android app store now open to developers. [Online]. Available: http://techcrunch.com/2011/01/05/amazon-android-app-store-2/.

[22] E. F. Konczal, Models are for managers, not mathematicians, Journal of Systems Management, vol. 26, no.1, pp. 12-15, 1975.

[23] F. Lin and W. Ye, Operating System Battle in the Ecosystem of Smartphone Industry, in Information Engineering and Electronic Commerce, 2009. International Symposium on, 2009, pp. 617-621.

[24] J. Magretta, Why business models matter, Harvard business review, vol. 80, pp. 86-93, May 2002.

[25] Microsoft, Press Release. (2011, February) Nokia and Microsoft Announce Plans for a Broad Strategic Partnership to Build a New Global Mobile Ecosystem. [Online]. Available: http://www.microsoft.com/presspass/press/2011/feb11/02-11partnership.mspx.

[26] R. R. Nelson and S. G. Winter, In search of useful theory of innovation, Research policy, vol. 6, no.1, pp. 36-76, 1977.

[27] R. R. Nelson and S. G. Winter, An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press, 1982.

[28] R. R. Nelson and S. G. Winter, Evolutionary theorizing in economics, Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol. 16,no. 2, pp. 23-46, 2002.

[29] A. Osterwalder and Y. Pigneur, Business Model Generation: A Handbook for Visionaries, Game Changers, and Challengers, NJ: Wiley, 2009.

[30] A. Osterwalder, Y. Pigneur, and C. Tucci, Clarifying business models: Origins, present, and future of the concept, Communications of the Association for Information Systems, vol. 16, no. 1, pp. 1-25, 2005.

[31] J. Peppard and A. Rylander, From value chain to value network: Insights for mobile operators, European Management Journal, vol. 24, no. 2-3, pp. 128-141, 2006.

[32] M. E. Porter, Strategy and the Internet, Harvard Business Review, vol. 79, pp. 63-76, 2001.

[33] P. Resnick, K. Kuwabara, R. Zeckhauser, and E. Friedman, Reputation systems, Communications of the ACM, vol. 43, no. 12, pp. 45-48, 2000.

[34] J.-C. Rochet and J. Tirole, Platform competition in two-sided markets, Journal of the European Economic Association, vol. 1, no. 4, pp. 990-1029, 2003.

[35] D. Schlagwein, D. Schoder, and K. Fischbach, Openness of information resources – A framework-based comparison of mobile platforms, in Proceedings of 18th European Conference on Information Systems Pretoria, South Africa, 2010, pp 1-16.

[36] B. F. Schmid and M. A. Lindemann, Elements of a reference model for electronic markets, in Proceedings of the Thirty-First Hawaii International Conference on System Sciences, Hawaii, 1998, pp. 193-201.

[37] P. Stähler, Geschäftsmodelle in der digitalen Ökonomie. Merkmale, Strategien und Auswirkungen, Lohmar: Josef Eul Verlag, 2002.

[38] H. R. Varian, Market for information goods, Discussion paper no. 99-e-9, Institute of Monetary and Economic Studies, Bank of Japan, Tokyo, Japan 1999.

[39] H. Weigand, P. Johannesson, B. Andersson, M. Bergholtz, A. Edirisuriya, and T. Ilayperuma, Strategic analysis using value modeling-the c3-value approach, in Proceedings of the Hawaii International Conference on System Sciences, 2007, pp. 2906.

[40] O. Williamson, Transaction cost economics, in Handbook of new institutional economics (C. Ménard and M. M. Shirley, Eds.), 2005, pp. 41-65.

[41] O. E. Williamson, Markets and hierarchies: some elementary considerations, The American Economic Review, vol. 63, no. 2, pp. 316-325, 1973.

[42] T. Wu, The Master Switch: The Rise and Fall of Information Empires. New York: Knopf, 2010.